no-arbitrage in the Black-Scholes pricing model
The underlying intuition behind the mechanics of the Black-Scholes formula, in simpler cases, can be described without recourse to stochastic calculus.
The two basic principles behind financial derivative pricing are:
-
i
A portfolio must be self-financing: “you cannot create money out of thin air”
-
ii
There should be no opportunities for arbitrage (a profit for any one of the parties involving absolutely no risk).
In the mathematically rigorous derivation, principle (i) is formalized as the stochastic differential equation on the value of the portfolio at time :
(1) |
Principle (ii) was not particularly emphasized in the formal derivation, but is a necessary consequence of our method of pricing a financial derivative instrument. Consider a contract agreed between two parties, at time , that stipulates the seller to make a payment of to the buyer of the contract at time ; the buyer pays at time to take advantage of this offer. The value , in general, depends on some risky (or volatile) asset such as a stock, so we cannot easily ascertain that the deal is fair or not.
But there is still a concept of a fair value for the contract. If the seller, having sold the contract, starts to immediately manage his investments in such a way as to mitigate all of the risk, then the initial capital for managing such investment must be the fair value of the contract. If the value paid by the buyer to the seller at time is larger than this fair value, then the seller makes a risk-free profit: he uses up some amount of the up-front fee to manage his investment portfolio, and he will always be able to meet his obligation to pay the buyer at time , yet still have some amount left over from the original fee that he can pocket.
Conversely, if the fair value turns out to be lower than the up-front fee offered, the buyer has taken advantage of the seller.
In the formal derivation of the Black-Scholes formula, the portfolio value at varying times represents the investment management decision, subject to the self-financing condition represented by equation (1). The terminal condition of the portfolio value at time is given and fixed to be exactly the seller’s obligation at that time; hence the seller of the contract is in a riskless position if he follows the appropriate investment decisions. Moreover, the stochastic differential equation has a unique solution at time : this is the initial capital required for the investment strategy that hedges away all risk. Thus, the method of solution of the stochastic differential equations of the Black-Scholes model incorporate the no-arbitrage principle.
In simple contracts, we can find out, by elementary reasoning, what the fair value should be.
Consider a forward contract, which is an agreement, made at time , for the buyer to obtain an asset at time in exchange for a payment of at time . Denote the value of the asset at various times by . The value of is known at the time of signing of the contract, but is a random variable, because the asset price is volatile.
The fair value of the forward contract is the value that would give the buyer and seller no distinct advantage compared to the situation when the buyer simply buys and pays for the asset at time .11So why does not the buyer simply acquire the asset at time ? Because in practice, it may be inconvenient or costly for the buyer to hold on to an asset that is not going to be used until at time . This is not much of an issue for stocks, which are paper assets, but it matters if the asset is a commodity such as energy — the buyer might not be able to store these, or need a significant amount of money to do so. Of course, in the theoretical reason presented here, we ignore all such transactional costs. If we are buying the asset, we can either get that asset now (at time ) for a price of , or decide to get it later (at time ), meanwhile stashing the equivalent amount of money () in the bank. In the latter situation, when we do get the asset at time , the money in our bank account is now , assuming continuous compounding at an interest rate of .
Hence we are prepared to pay when buying the asset forward. This is the price of the forward contract. Note that it does not involve the price , because that price is random and unknown when we sign the contract. It is not even the expected future price , because there is certainly no guarantee that will take on the value .
(more to be written…)
Title | no-arbitrage in the Black-Scholes pricing model |
---|---|
Canonical name | NoarbitrageInTheBlackScholesPricingModel |
Date of creation | 2013-03-22 16:54:04 |
Last modified on | 2013-03-22 16:54:04 |
Owner | stevecheng (10074) |
Last modified by | stevecheng (10074) |
Numerical id | 4 |
Author | stevecheng (10074) |
Entry type | Topic |
Classification | msc 91B28 |
Classification | msc 60H10 |