Black-Scholes PDE
Contents:
The Black-Scholes partial differential equation is the partial differentiation equation:
rf=∂f∂t+rx∂f∂x+12σ2x2∂2f∂x2,f=f(t,x), | (1) |
on the domain 0≤x<∞, 0≤t≤T.
Its solution gives the price function
of a stock option (or any other contingent claim on a tradable asset)
under the assumptions of the Black-Scholes model for prices.
The parameters r, σ>0 and T>0 are, respectively, the prevailing continuously-compounded risk-free rate of interest, the volatility of the stock, and the time to maturity of the stock option.
More generally, the term Black-Scholes partial differential equation
can refer to other partial differential equations
similar in form to equation (1), derived
in similar ways under more
general modelling assumptions than the most basic Black-Scholes model.
0.1 Derivation from martingale form
The Black-Scholes formula, in its martingale form,
gives the theoretical value of the stock option
V(t)=e-r(T-t)𝔼ℚ[V(T)∣ℱt],0≤t≤T, | (2) |
where V(T) is a given pay-off function
or terminal condition, assumed to be a 𝐋1(ℚ) random variable;
ℱt is the filtration
generated by the the standard Wiener
process
˜W(t)
under the probability measure
ℚ (the “risk-neutral measure”).
Equation (2) gives the solution to the stochastic differential equations:
V(t) | =Δ(t)X(t)+Θ(t)M(t),M(t)=ert, | (3) | ||
dV(t) | =Δ(t)dX(t)+Θ(t)dM(t),dM(t)=rM(t)dt, | (4) | ||
dX(t) | =rX(t)dt+σX(t)d˜W(t). | (5) |
From the martingale form of the result, there are two ways to derive the PDE form (1).
0.1.1 Using the Feynman-Kac formula
One way is to appeal to the Feynman-Kac formula, which states in this case, that under certain regularity conditions11 The standard assumption is that ψ is twice continuously-differentiable and 𝔼ℚ[|ψ(X(T))|]<∞. However, for the particular PDE we consider, these assumptions can be relaxed. on the function ψ:(0,∞)→ℝ, the function f:[0,T]×(0,∞)→ℝ defined by
f(t,x)=e-r(T-t)𝔼ℚ[ψ(X(T))∣X(t)=x], | (6) |
satisfies the partial differential equation (1) with the terminal condition
f(T,x)=ψ(x). |
(The stochastic process X(t)
is to satisfy equation (5).)
Now, equations (6) and (2)
look quite similar,
but with an important difference:
the conditional expectation on equation (6)
is with respect to the event {X(t)=x},
while equation (2)
is conditioning on the filtration ℱt.
We claim that these are actually the same thing —
that is, for fixed t, the random variable
𝔼ℚ[V(T)∣ℱt]
can be written as a function of X(t) —
provided that the terminal condition is itself a function of X(T):
V(T)=ψ(X(T)). |
We will demonstrate this claim later. Assuming that the claim holds, we may thus set V(t)=f(t,X(t)), and the Black-Scholes partial differential equation follows from the Feynman-Kac formula as explained earlier.
0.1.2 Proof of Markov property
Formally, any ℱt-measurable stochastic process
X(t) that
ensures 𝔼[ψ(X(T))∣ℱt]
is always a measurable function of X(t),
for any Borel-measurable ψ,
is called a Markov process,
or is said to have the Markov property.
Thus we want to show that the stock process X(t) has
the Markov property.
For this,
we will need the following explicit
solution for it at time T
in terms of an initial condition
at time t:
X(T) | =X(t)exp((r-12σ2)(T-t)+σ(˜W(T)-˜W(t))) | ||
:= |
Then
Since is -measurable, it may be treated as a constant while taking conditional expectations with respect to . And is a random variable independent of (and hence of ). Therefore the expression that appears on the right-hand side above is a function of , and would be unchanged if the conditioning is changed from to .
0.1.3 Using Itō’s formula
Set
as before.
Make the assumption that is twice continuously differentiable,
to be checked later; then we can apply Itō’s formula to expand :
(partial derivatives evaluated at )
(7) |
By theorems on the uniqueness of solutions to stochastic differential
equations, the coefficients of the
correponding and
terms in equations (4) and (7)
must be equal almost surely.
Equating the coefficients, we find:
(8) | ||||
(9) |
Equation (9)
is essentially equation (1),
except that has been replaced by in some places.
However,
because is a random variable that takes on all values on ,
and and its derivatives are assumed to be continuous
,
equation (9) must hold for arbitrary values
substituted for . Hence we obtain equation (1).
To verify the initial assumption that is twice continuously differentiable, we write formula (2) in a more explicit form (using the Markov property for as before):
where is the transition density of the
stock process from to over a time interval of length .
In fact, from the solution for ,
the density
is the density for the log-normal random variable
whose logarithm has mean
and variance .
By differentiation under the integral sign,
we see that must be twice continously differentiable
for and .
0.2 Comparison of the martingale and PDE forms
The martingale formulation of the result,
in equation (2)
is more general than the PDE formulation (1):
the latter imposes extra regularity conditions,
and more importantly,
it can only describe prices
that are
functions only of the time and the current stock price .
In the case of the call option ( for some ),
this assumption is true;
but there are other sorts of contingent claims
whose pay-off depend on the history of the stock process —
for example, a common kind of contingent claim has a final
pay-off that depends on an average
of the stock price over time .
However, the PDE form of the solution is often more amenable to a numerical solution. While the expectation in equation (2) can be approximated numerically with Monte-Carlo simulation, for low-dimensional problems, solutions based on finite-difference approximations of PDEs are often quicker to compute than those based on Monte-Carlo.
0.3 Analytic solution
Though the solution for the Black-Scholes PDE is already known using the martingale representation (2), we can also solve the PDE directly using classical analytical methods (http://planetmath.org/AnalyticSolutionOfBlackScholesPDE).
Actually, the classical solution can be quite instructive in that it shows more or less the physical meaning behind the PDE, and also the behavior of solutions as the terminal condition is varied. (For example, the PDE is a transformation of a diffusion equation, and consequently its solutions are always infinitely smooth, as long as the terminal condition satisfies some local-integrability properties.)
0.4 Quantity of stock needed to replicate option
Another important result that must not be left unmentioned is equation (8), derived during the course of showing the Black-Scholes PDE.
In the article on the Black-Scholes pricing formula,
a solution for was produced
that satisfied (4),
but the -adapted process
that appears in that stochastic differential equation was
obtained by appealing to an existence theorem.
However, under the assumption that ,
equation (8) gives an actual computable formula:
which is crucial in practice, for the theoretical “price” of a stock option would be useless if one cannot produce in reality that option for the stated price.
0.5 Generalizations
(To be written.)
Title | Black-Scholes PDE |
---|---|
Canonical name | BlackScholesPDE |
Date of creation | 2013-03-22 16:31:08 |
Last modified on | 2013-03-22 16:31:08 |
Owner | stevecheng (10074) |
Last modified by | stevecheng (10074) |
Numerical id | 6 |
Author | stevecheng (10074) |
Entry type | Result |
Classification | msc 91B28 |
Classification | msc 60H10 |
Synonym | Black-Scholes partial differential equation |
Synonym | Black-Scholes equation |
Related topic | AnalyticSolutionOfBlackScholesPDE |
Related topic | ExampleOfSolvingTheHeatEquation |